Thursday, September 4, 2014

What do exchange rates measure?


Scott Sumner says that because the ECB lowered interest rates and reduced IOR -- and since the Euro fell on that news -- the ECB (i.e. monetary policy) is capable of producing inflation and that the zero lower bound/liquidity trap is incorrect.

That sure sounds like a coherent theory, but is it the only one? And what does a falling price of a Euro in terms of e.g. dollars mean? This sounds like a perfect opportunity to take on exchange rates with the information transfer model.

I first looked at a naive model where the exchange rate is based on the ratio [1] of the supply of each currency and got a not entirely terrible fit (exchange rate data is in orange and the ratio is in blue):


However this model only works with the supply of Euros in the numerator! This is weird because it means if the supply of Euros goes up, the dollar price of a Euro also goes up. Or in terms of macro, if the exchange rate (dollar price of a euro) goes up it means the supply of base money Euros increased implying inflation. That would mean (when Sumner reasons from a price change above) that if the exchange rate falls on an ECB announcement (meaning Fed policy can be taken as constant) we should expect a fall in the supply of base Euros and deflation -- on news of expansionary monetary policy, no less!

How do we make sense of this? The dollar price of Euro goes up when there are more Euros -- that must mean demand for Euros has gone up. That's the key insight here. Let's start from the basic information transfer model:

$$
\frac{dD_{EU}}{dM0_{EU}} = P_{EU} = k_{EU} \frac{D_{EU}}{M0_{EU}}
$$

where $D_{EU}$ is the demand for Euros, $M0_{EU}$ is the amount of Euro currency in circulation and $P_{EU}$ is the "price" of a Euro (the Platonic ideal price that we'll later compare to another price to determine an exchange rate). We can solve this differential equation to obtain:

$$
D_{EU} \sim {M0_{EU}}^{k_{EU}}
$$

and

$$
P_{EU} \sim k_{EU} {M0_{EU}}^{k_{EU}-1}
$$

We can solve the analogous model for the dollar demand and obtain:

$$
P_{US} \sim k_{US} {M0_{US}}^{k_{US}-1}
$$

The exchange rate is then the ratio of these prices

$$
X_{EU,US} = \frac{P_{EU}}{P_{US}} = \alpha \frac{{M0_{EU}}^{k_{EU}-1}}{{M0_{US}}^{k_{US}-1}}
$$

where $\alpha$ is a constant fit to the data like $k_{EU}$ and $k_{US}$. This now makes sense of exhange rate price movements -- if the dollar price (exchange rate) of a Euro goes up it means that the price (value) $P_{EU}$ of a Euro has gone up (supply has decreased or demand has increased) or the price (value) of a dollar $P_{US}$ has gone down (supply has increased or demand has decreased).

In addition to making sense, it also fits the data pretty well (with nice Gaussian residuals):


And not just for the Euro -- here is the Yen-Dollar exchange rate:


The other key takeaway from this analysis is that exchange rate moves are not always relevant to inflation. Since $X$ is a function of $M0$ [2] and moves in $M0$ do not always lead to inflation (especially in a liquidity trap/information trap), moves in $X$ do not indicate monetary policy effectiveness or inflation. Long term interest rates will probably fall in the Eurozone, which may help the fiscal situations of several member states, but there does not appear to be any monetary impact from the ECB's announcement.

Another way to say this is that printing money will impact exchange rates, but may not impact inflation if you are in a liquidity trap. One could say that exchange rates and inflation decouple in a liquidity trap.

It's also important to note that the fluctuations in the exchange rates are large, so any particular move is unlikely to be very informative ... never reason from a price change.


Footnotes:

[1] We could imagine this as a purely exogenous information transfer model where P = k D/S (where P is the price or exchange rate, D is the demand and S is the supply).

[2] The other measures of money are also decent models, for example, here are the M2 versions:


But I've shown before that log M2 ~ k log M0 so this doesn't actually add information (we can just re-write the M2 versions of the equations in terms of M0).


9 comments:

  1. Jason, you are by far the hardest working amateur econ blogger out there! Lol... or the scary thing is you aren't... you just have an incredibly easy time jumping from one analysis to another. Bravo sir!

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Thanks Tom!

      Once I built a Mathematica function to import FRED data, everything got a little easier :)

      Delete
    2. Did you really mean "base" in your comment to Scott? He replied BTW

      http://www.themoneyillusion.com/?p=27438#comment-363651

      Delete
    3. I sometimes get tired of writing "currency component of the base", to my own chagrin ...

      I responded back at Sumner's blog.

      Delete
    4. ... you could just shorten it to "currency." I don't think anybody cares about bales of uncirculated currency at the BEP or the Fed.

      Delete
    5. Yes, but Sumner usually refers to "base money" where the large increases in reserves aren't 'expected' to be a part of it :)

      Delete
    6. He came back with another one liner.

      Delete
    7. "Eurozone inflation makes the dollar price of euros fall, not rise."

      This is not empirically true (as shown above) -- we have Xeu,us ∝ M0eu and P ∝ M0eu. And the reason it is not true is that both supply and demand matter.

      Delete
    8. Jason, I read that "conversation" between you and Scott about four times... scratching my head at his response. I felt like I wanted to explain to him what you found, but what you're saying takes a little bit of thought to understand... not much, but a little... so I just alerted you and left it alone. I couldn't figure out how to write something which wouldn't get a one liner reply (if any).

      Yes, that's a very succinct way to put it.

      Delete

Comments are welcome. Please see the Moderation and comment policy.

Also, try to avoid the use of dollar signs as they interfere with my setup of mathjax. I left it set up that way because I think this is funny for an economics blog. You can use € or £ instead.

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.