Thursday, November 5, 2015

Monkeys and markets

So I found out my Dad reads the blog, and he sent me a link to an article from about 10 years ago about observing capuchin monkeys engaging in market behavior set up by experimenters. Previously I noted that E. coli also exhibits something like supply and demand.

I showed you could get this behavior from random agents, based primarily on the properties of the available state space. It turns out my contribution wasn't original as Gary Becker had also worked this out in the 1960s (and economists responded negatively to giving up the idea of utility maximization).

The implicit theorizing in the article is great:
It took several months of rudimentary repetition to teach the monkeys that these tokens were valuable as a means of exchange for a treat and would be similarly valuable the next day. Having gained that understanding, a capuchin would then be presented with 12 tokens on a tray and have to decide how many to surrender for, say, Jell-O cubes versus grapes. This first step allowed each capuchin to reveal its preferences and to grasp the concept of budgeting. 
Then Chen introduced price shocks and wealth shocks. If, for instance, the price of Jell-O fell (two cubes instead of one per token), would the capuchin buy more Jell-O and fewer grapes? The capuchins responded rationally to tests like this -- that is, they responded the way most readers of The Times would respond. In economist-speak, the capuchins adhered to the rules of utility maximization and price theory: when the price of something falls, people tend to buy more of it.
Revealed preferences, budget constraint, price shocks, rational responses, utility maximization: the whole framework is there. Even intertemporal expectations ("similarly valuable the next day"). Note that the axiom of revealed preference is equivalent to assuming real-valued utility functions (ensuring transitivity creates a total order which means that whatever it is, it can be represented with real numbers if it's not pathological).

Of course, you can get these results just from the properties of the state space. Start with 12 tokens and look at the available state space for Jell-O (quantity Q₁) with a price of 0.8 token, 1 token and 2 tokens. If the monkeys chose a budget completely at random in the available state space, they'd on average choose the point (colored points) at the center of the area bounded by the budget constraint (colored lines):


If we change the price of Jell-O from 2 to 1 and then 0.8 token, we move (on average) from the red point to the blue point to the green point. Plotting these out in price-quantity space, we get a downward sloping demand curve:


Apparent rational behavior from averaging random choices.

Note that if you add dimensions, i.e. different goods (grapes, Jell-O, crackers, chocolate, beer, ...), the centroids approach the budget constraint lines (most of the volume of a high dimensional space is near its surface), and the random choice approximates utility maximization if you consider utility functions that aren't too asymmetric.

2 comments:

  1. Great!... if you recall I asked you a question about applicability of ITM to non-human animal economics a long time ago. It's great to see this.

    ReplyDelete
  2. Some experiments were done in the 1950s or 60s in which chimpanzees worked for tokens, which they inserted into vending machines for food. And yes, according to our prof, tokens were exchanged for sex. :)

    ReplyDelete

Comments are welcome. Please see the Moderation and comment policy.

Also, try to avoid the use of dollar signs as they interfere with my setup of mathjax. I left it set up that way because I think this is funny for an economics blog. You can use € or £ instead.

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.