There was some good discussion in comments on the previous post; I thought I'd summarize some aspects of the information transfer model (ITM) brought up by John Handley (on the components of the model involved in the growth rate) and LAL (on the business cycle). The overall model shows that without the recessions and the ITM trend, the fluctuations in RGDP growth do not have unit root -- which means they are essentially random fluctuations with zero mean. This means we can look at RGDP growth as the sum of three components:
These three components are pictured above:
Noise (in gray). Random fluctuations around the ideal growth path. It may be entirely measurement error or fundamental fluctuations because the economy is (in physics terms) a mesoscopic system with the system size N > 1, but not N >> 1. Note that this is simulated with a normal distribution with standard deviation of 2 (percentage points) and mean of zero.
Non-ideal information transfer (recessions, dashed blue). This is the component that is least understood in terms of the model itself. The ITM allows non-ideal information transfer, but doesn't tell us what it looks like. The piece I put here is a guess (it's a step function on the leading edge and a Fermi distribution on the trailing edge). Although it is uncertain at this point how much of these recessions are real shock and how much are human emotion. More on that here.
Ideal information transfer (information equilibrium, solid blue). This is the trend of GDP that falls out of the partition function approach (or just treating it as a line in NGDP-M0 space). RGDP slowly falls because as an economy grows, a given dollar is more and more likely to be found facilitating a transaction in a low growth market. I just simulated this with a slowly falling function here.
You can sum them up to produce these pictures of the growth rate and the level:
With this interpretation there really isn't a thing that I'd call a "business cycle". Going back to the sandpile analogy we have a randomly fluctuating flow of sand with an average rate. The height of the sand pile grows, but more slowly over time. Every once in awhile there is an avalanche and the height drops by more than usual. There is a cycle in the sense that the growth rate becomes negative and then positive again when avalanches occur. But instead of referring to the "sandpile height cycle", I'd personally just refer to "avalanches". By analogy, there isn't a "business cycle", but rather occasional "adverse shocks". Those shocks may be entirely random (although I have a speculative theory they are not in the sense that you can predict an increasing likelihood of shock ... and interest rates look like a good indicator too).
As a postscript, John Handley did have one question about the moving average that was the subject of the last post. The Great Recession looks like it permanently lowers the average growth rate in the graphs in that post. However that is just an artefact of using a 10-year window when the Great Recession was less than 10 years in the past. In the simulation above, I use a 5 year window to show that the effect of the lower average goes away when the shock leaves your averaging window (black line):
I also show the average rate using Cochrane's original method (gray). It comes out a bit higher as it did in the previous post.
Already at the 5 year window the percent change doesn't seem as bad as his 10 year did...
ReplyDeleteBut anyway, what is the moral of the story, should we be looking at moving averages as a proxy to understand growth in the economy? Or are we primarily interested in them to shut out the noise? (Which I think fits your criticism of Cochrane) what statistic should I be looking at to understand when drops are occurring in your sandy plucking model?
I think that the moral, as far as moving averages go, is don't put too much weight on the end points of your data.
Delete