Sunday, March 16, 2014

Nick Rowe's model of the money stock

Suppose, just suppose, that the central bank does target an exogenously fixed rate of interest, and ignore the Wicksellian indeterminacy this creates, and ignore the fact that this is incompatible with targeting inflation or anything vaguely sensible. That interest rate target is the central bank's supply function, and a change in that interest rate target supply function will cause a change in the stock of money. 
Will it be true that the actual stock of money will always be equal to and determined by the quantity of money demanded at that target rate of interest? ... "no".
That's from Nick Rowe's post today. This is basically true if you set up an inverted version of the information transfer model. Previously, I had taken the monetary base as input (exogenous, in economic language), so that: 

rs = r(NGDP, MB)
rl = r(NGDP, M0)
P = P(NGDP, M0)

(That's not a typo, the function r is the same for the long term, say 10-year, rate rl and short run, say 3-month rate rs.) NGDP is exogenous, and as it is set up, Prs and rl are endogenous.

Rowe sets up a system with an endogenous monetary base, effectively inverting the first two equations above:

MB = M(NGDP, rs)
M0 = M(NGDP, rl)
P = P(NGDP, M0)

with the same function M. Allowing non-ideal information transfer, the actual monetary base should be less than the quantity demanded (the solution to the equations) at the target rate of interest, answering the question at the end of the quotation above. What happens if we insert the effective Fed funds rate (this is approximately equal to the Fed target rate) for rs and the empirical 10-year rate for rl? Here is the Fed funds rate:


Here is the resulting monetary base (including reserves); the model is the solid line, while the actual value of the base is the dashed line:


Here is the resulting currency component of the monetary base (excluding reserves); the model is the solid line, while the actual value of the base is the dashed line:


It is in this last graph that the actual currency component is smaller than the quantity demanded. However, if we were to fit the model parameters to the short term interest rate, then the previous graph would show that the base including reserves demanded was always less greater than the actual monetary base. In fact, here it is (using the model fit to the short term interest rate to set the parameters):

For fun, here are the plots of the price level fit to these endogenous monetary bases (using the original fit to the long run interest rate):


It works reasonably well for the price level, but does show that an interest rate inflation target is nigh impossible due to the fluctuations.

Update 4/5/2014: the "less than" crossed out above should have been "greater than". H/T Tom Brown.

6 comments:

  1. In the last line, I should say that an inflation target is nigh impossible with endogenous money/interest rate target due to the fluctuations.

    ReplyDelete
  2. Jason,

    "It is in this last graph that the actual currency component is smaller than the quantity demanded. However, if we were to fit the model parameters to the short term interest rate, then the previous graph would show that the base including reserves demanded was always less than the actual monetary base. In fact, here it is (using the model fit to the short term interest rate to set the parameters):"

    Should that read:
    "then the previous graph would show that the base including reserves demanded was always greater than the actual monetary base."

    Also it's interesting to me that the solid lines are the model and the dashed ones the data, since the solid lines have a lot more bumps and such on them, which I typically associate with empirical data.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. You are correct about the "less than". Thank goodness for graphs showing what one actually means.

      Regarding the solid and dashed lines, this is because the model derived the base from empirical interest rate data (a very noisy function) and compared it to the actual base (a relatively smooth one, if one includes seasonal adjustments) or the core CPI (another relatively smooth function, including SA). You can think of the results as modeling the demand for base money which fluctuates based on human behavior. This would be a lot more volatile than the amounts of physical currency.

      The model in this case (the second set of three equations) is inverted from the way I usually present it (the first set of three equations), so it changes what the inputs (endogenous variables) and the outputs (exogenous variables) are.

      Delete
  3. This comment has been removed by the author.

    ReplyDelete
  4. i would like to ask you what your model looks like which you used to plot the graphs 2,3 and 4?

    Thank you

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Sorry for the delay in getting back to you -- I was on vacation and have only just returned.

      The information equilibrium relationship connecting the effective fed funds rate e, nominal output N, and the monetary base MB results in the equation

      log(e) = c1 log(N/MB) + b1

      with c1 = 3.7 and b1 = -13.7 (best fit parameters). The 10-year rate r is given by

      log(r) = c2 log(N/M0) + b2

      with c2 = 2.7 and b2 = -10.9 (best fit parameters) and M0 is the currency component of the base.

      Graph 2 inverts the first equation so that

      log(MB) = (1/c1)*(c1 log(N) - log(e) + b1)

      and compares the computed MB with data. Graph 3 inverts the second equation so that

      log(M0) = (1/c2)*(c2 log(N) - log(r) + b2)

      and compares the computed M0 with data. Graph 4 does the same thing but uses the coefficients from the second equation (c2 instead of c1, b2 instead of b1):

      log(MB) = (1/c2)*(c2 log(N) - log(e) + b2)

      Regards,

      Jason

      Delete

Comments are welcome. Please see the Moderation and comment policy.

Also, try to avoid the use of dollar signs as they interfere with my setup of mathjax. I left it set up that way because I think this is funny for an economics blog. You can use € or £ instead.

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.