Monday, February 23, 2015

Information equilibrium paper (draft) (macroeconomics)


Since I apparently can't seem to sit down and write anything that isn't on a blog, I thought I'd create a few posts that I will edit in real time (feel free to comment) until I can copy and paste them into a document to put on the arXiv and/or submit to the economics e-journal (H/T to Todd Zorick for helping to motivate me).

WARNING: DRAFT: This post may be updated without any indications of changes. It will be continuously considered a draft.
Macroeconomics

Since the information equilibrium framework depends on a large number of states for the information source and destination, it ostensibly would be better applied to the macroeconomic problem. Below are some classic macroeconomic toy models (and one macroeconomic relationship): AD-AS model, Okun's law, the IS-LM model, and the Solow growth model. 

[To be added, the price level/quantity theory of money]

AD-AS

The AD-AS model uses the price level $P$ as the detector, aggregate demand $N$ (NGDP) as the information source and aggregate supply $S$ as the destination, or $P:N \rightarrow S$, which immediately allows us to write down the aggregate demand and aggregate supply curves

$$
P = \frac{N_{0}}{k_{A} S_{ref}} \exp \left( - k_{A} \frac{\Delta N}{N_{0}} \right)
$$

$$
P = \frac{N_{ref}}{k_{A} S_{0}} \exp \left( + \frac{\Delta S}{k_{A} S_{0}} \right)
$$

Positive shifts in the aggregate demand curve raise the price level along with negative shifts in the supply curve. Traveling along the aggregate demand curve lowers the price level (more aggregate supply at constant demand).


Labor market and Okun's law

The labor market uses the price level $P$ as the detector, aggregate demand $N$ as the information source and total hours worked $H$ (or total employed $L$) as the destination. We have the market $P:N \rightarrow H$ so that we can say:

$$
P = \frac{1}{k_{H}} \; \frac{N}{H}
$$

Re-arranging and taking the logarithmic derivative of both sides:

$$
H = \frac{1}{k_{H}} \; \frac{N}{P}
$$

$$
\frac{d}{dt} \log H = \frac{d}{dt} \log \frac{N}{P} - \frac{d}{dt} \log k_{H}
$$

$$
\frac{d}{dt} \log H = \frac{d}{dt} \log \frac{N}{P} - 0 = \frac{d}{dt} \log R
$$

where $R$ is RGDP. The total hours worked (or total employed) fluctuates with the change in RGDP growth (Okun's law).


IS-LM

The IS-LM model uses two markets along with an information equilibrium relationship. Let $p$ be the price of money in the money market (LM market) $p:N \rightarrow M$ where $N$ is aggregate demand and $M$ is the money supply.

We have:

$$
p = \frac{1}{k_{p}} \; \frac{N}{M}
$$

We assume that the interest rate $i$ is in information equilibrium with the price of money $p$, so that we have the information equilibrium relationship $i \rightarrow p$ (no need to define a detector at this point). Therefore the differential equation is:

$$
\frac{di}{dp} = \frac{1}{k_{i}} \; \frac{i}{p}
$$

With solution (we won't need the additional constants $p_{ref}$ or $i_{ref}$):

$$
i^{k_{i}} = p
$$

And we can write [note: this is a new take (here's the old take) on the constant $k_{i}$ that I've called $c$]:

$$
i^{k_i} = \frac{1}{k_{p}}  \; \frac{N}{M}
$$

Already this is pretty empirically accurate:


We can now rewrite the money (LM) market and add the goods (IS) market as coupled markets with the same information source (aggregate demand) and same detector (interest rate, directly related to -- i.e. in information equilibrium with -- the price of money):

$$
i^{k_i} : N \rightarrow M
$$
$$
i^{k_i} : N \rightarrow S
$$

Where $S$ is the aggregate supply. The LM market is described by both increases in the money supply $M$ shifts as well as shifts in the information source $N_{0} \rightarrow N_{0} + \Delta N$, so we write the LM curve as a demand curve, with shifts:

$$
i^{k_i} = \frac{N_{0} + \Delta N}{k_{p} M_{ref}} \exp \left( - k_{p} \frac{\Delta M}{N_{0} + \Delta N} \right)
$$

The IS curve can be straight-forwardly be written down as the demand curve in the IS market:

$$
i^{k_i} = \frac{N_{0}}{k_{S} S_{ref}} \exp \left( - k_{S} \frac{\Delta N}{N_{0}} \right)
$$


Solow growth model

Let's assume two markets $p_{1}:N \rightarrow K$ and $p_{2}:N \rightarrow L$:

$$
\text{(3a) }\frac{\partial N}{\partial K} = \frac{1}{\kappa_{1}}\; \frac{N}{K}
$$

$$
\text{(3b) }\frac{\partial N}{\partial L} = \frac{1}{\kappa_{2}}\; \frac{N}{L}
$$

The economics rationale for equations (3a,b) are that the left hand sides are the marginal productivity of capital/labor which are assumed to be proportional to the right hand sides -- the productivity per unit capital/labor. In the information transfer model, the relationship follows from a model of aggregate demand sending information to aggregate supply (capital and labor) where the information transfer is "ideal" i.e. no information loss. The solutions are:

$$
N(K, L) \sim f(L) K^{1/\kappa_{1}}
$$

$$
N(K, L) \sim g(K) L^{1/\kappa_{2}}
$$

and therefore we have

$$
\text{(4) } N(K, L) = A  K^{1/\kappa_{1}} L^{1/\kappa_{2}}
$$

Equation (4) is the generic Cobb-Douglas form. In this case, unlike equation (2), the exponents are free to take on any value (nor restricted to constant returns to scale, i.e. $1/\kappa_{1} + 1/\kappa_{2} = 1$). The resulting model is remarkably accurate:


It also has no changes in so-called total factor productivity ($A$ is constant). The results above use nominal capital and nominal GDP $N$ rather than the usual real capital and real output (RGDP, $R$).

Summary

We have shown that several macroeconomic relationships and toy models can be easily represented using the information equilibrium framework, and in fact are remarkably accurate empirically. Below we list a summary of the information equilibrium models in the notation

detector : source → destination

i.e. price : demand → supply. Also the information equilibrium models that do not require detectors are shown as 

source → destination.

The models shown here are:

AD-AS model

$$
P: N \rightarrow S
$$

Labor market (Okun's law)

$$
P: N \rightarrow H
$$
or

$$
P: N \rightarrow L
$$

IS-LM model

$$
(i \rightarrow p ) : N \rightarrow M
$$
$$
i : N \rightarrow S
$$

Solow growth model

$$
N \rightarrow K
$$
$$
N \rightarrow L
$$

7 comments:

  1. Note: except where the results are compared to empirical data, the derivation of the model using the information equilibrium framework does not imply that the model is correct.

    The results here are more like writing down a quantum field theory and showing how it works than they constitute "proof" of the IS-LM or AD-AS models.

    ReplyDelete
  2. I recently discovered this blog. It's a gem in that the writing and mathematics are accessible to laymen. Too many economics blogs are either readable by everyone or only for academics. The balance here is refreshing.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Thanks, Jefftopia. I would caution that while some of the results are perfectly consistent with 'mainstream' economic ideas, the methods are not mainstream at all.

      However, I have considered that this approach may be better pedagogically than current approaches even if it ends up not having an application to e.g. policy. The math is at a high school calculus to undergraduate college level so is just right for an intro to economics course.

      Delete
  3. can the models be simultaneously fit to the data?

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Yes, but it's actually trivial for the most part as simultaneous model simply consists of direct products. The only case that I need to look at more closely is if the Solow growth model information equilibrium condition p2 : N → L and the labor market model equilibrium condition P : N → L are consistent, but as the price p2 isn't used, there is no reason we can't take p2 = P. I will explicitly do the simultaneous fit and post it soon.

      Delete
    2. One place the simultaneous model isn't just a trivial direct product is the combination of the price level and LM market models P : N → M and i : N → M ... it explains why interest rates went up and then down over the post war period:

      http://informationtransfereconomics.blogspot.com/2014/03/the-effects-that-move-interest-rates.html

      Delete

Comments are welcome. Please see the Moderation and comment policy.

Also, try to avoid the use of dollar signs as they interfere with my setup of mathjax. I left it set up that way because I think this is funny for an economics blog. You can use € or £ instead.

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.