Monday, August 1, 2016

The Economy at the End of the Universe

Nick Rowe presented a model [as a reductio ad abusrdum] where it appears as though the limit of a series of finite horizons differs by a greater and greater amount from the infinite time horizon model. I think this is just another illustration of how you really have to be careful when taking limits in economics -- some limits make no economic sense.

Here's a graph Nick's model where an interest rate r increase causes the price level P(t) to suddenly drop in order for the path of P(t) to conform to the Fisher equation. The lines represent longer and longer (but finite) time horizons:


You can see that a longer time horizon means you need a larger immediate drop in the price level. Does this make economic sense? If the time horizon is 70 years in the future, the drop in P(t) is 50; if it is 140 years, the drop in P(t) is 75. Imagine a bunch of firms with different time horizons. Firms with longer time horizons will drop their prices more based on the same 100 basis point increase in the interest rate? This seems odd.

That's because there's another limit being taken that happens before the infinite time horizon limit -- the rate at which prices drop increases with T. Here's a graph that approaches Nick's version as T goes to infinity:


The initial drop in P(t) gets faster and faster in order to drop farther and farther as T goes to infinity. But why should the rate at which prices adjust to a monetary shock get faster with longer time horizons? Maybe there is a good reason. In any case, that is the implicit model of firm behavior in Nick's limit of finite horizons.

And even if this is a good model in a particular finite case, at T equal to infinity we have an infinite (fractional) drop in the price level and an infinitely long climb back up to some finite value. That is to say the limit of Nick's function as T goes to infinity is a step function (black dashed line below). Here I show you the graphs on a linear scale (with double the original time horizons) to make it more obvious:


The price level is the function:
P(t) = 100 for all t < 0 and t = 0
P(t) = 0 for all 0 < t < ∞
P(∞) = 100
With the exception of that point at infinity, this is perfectly consistent with a price level that falls to zero for t > 0. That is to say Nick's model nearly everywhere is consistent with an expectation at infinity of zero! The difference between E[P(∞)] = 100 and E[P(∞)] = 0 is a single point at infinity. This makes it difficult to argue that this model faithfully represents a limit of finite time horizons with an E[P(∞)] = 100 -- in the limit the model only satisfies P(t) = 100 - ɛ for ɛ > 0 at t = ∞.

In other words, this is kind of a mathematical trick. The function satisfies the basic constraints -- i.e. E[P(∞)] = 100 -- but in a way that doesn't make economic sense. The infinite time horizon limit is an economy that collapses after a 100 basis point interest rate hike only to reappear for an instant just for the patrons at the Restaurant at the End of the Universe.

6 comments:

  1. Jason: I *think* I follow you. But one thing you need to be clear on: "Nick's model" isn't really *Nick's* model. I think it's a not very sensible model. The point of my post was to argue that that model doesn't make economic sense.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Hi Nick,

      I did understand that it was a reductio ad absurdum (I added a bit of text to explicitly state that at the beginning of this post).

      My point was supposed to be that it might not be a *fair* reductio ad absurdum because there aren't times t0 > 0 in the distant future that are close to P = 100 when the horizon is at infinity. Most of the neo-Fisher models I've seen have a long approach to the expected value at infinity so that there is some time t0 such that P = 100 - ɛ for some arbitrarily small ɛ. In math terms, the price level or inflation asymptotically approaches the expected value. The reductio ad absurdum you present does not.

      This is not to say I buy the neo-Fisher argument!

      Delete
  2. BTW, it would be neat to see similar graphs of my second model, that I describe briefly at the end of my post, the one I think does make sense (though it's oversimplified). The one where M(t)/P(t) is positive, but a negative function of (P(t+1)-P(t))/P(t). (Choose some easy functional form).

    ReplyDelete
  3. "you really have to be careful when taking limits in economics -- some limits make no economic sense."

    That's true in general, not just for economics. It is always a good idea to start with finite models and take them to the limit.

    ReplyDelete

Comments are welcome. Please see the Moderation and comment policy.

Also, try to avoid the use of dollar signs as they interfere with my setup of mathjax. I left it set up that way because I think this is funny for an economics blog. You can use € or £ instead.

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.