Thursday, January 19, 2017

Nick Rowe's view of the AD/AS model


Nick Rowe wrote up a short interpretation of the AD/AS model (aggregate demand/aggregate supply) that he thinks captures some deep understanding in macroeconomics. I'd like to show how to understand Nick's understanding in terms of information equilibrium.

*  *  *
Nick Rowe: The AD/AS framework is useful for thinking about monetary exchange economies.
Nick reiterates the point at the end, which is where I will take issue with it. However, let's set up an AD/AS information equilibrium condition $\Pi : AD \rightleftarrows AS$ with information transfer index $k$ such that

$$
\Pi \equiv \frac{dAD}{dAS} = k \; \frac{AD}{AS}
$$

where $\Pi$ is the price level.

*  *  *
Nick Rowe: Money (as medium of exchange) is different from all other assets. There is a flow of money into our pockets (and bank accounts) whenever we sell any other good (or asset). And there is a flow out of our pockets whenever we buy any other good.
In information transfer jargon, this tells us money $M$ is mediates information transfer between $AD$ and $AS$ (it isn't part of AD/AS) so that

$$
AD \rightleftarrows M \rightleftarrows AS
$$

and (via the chain rule and using $M/M = 1$)

$$
\Pi = \frac{dAD}{dAS} = \frac{dAD}{dM} \frac{dM}{dAS} = k \; \frac{AD}{M} \frac{M}{AS}
$$

We can separate these into two information equilibrium relationships $P_{1} : AD \rightleftarrows M$ and $P_{2} : M \rightleftarrows AS$:

$$
\begin{align}
P_{1} \equiv \frac{dAD}{dM} & = k_{1} \; \frac{AD}{M}\\
P_{2} \equiv \frac{dM}{dAS} & = k_{2} \; \frac{M}{AS}
\end{align}
$$

where

$$
\begin{align}
\Pi & = P_{1} P_{2}\\
k & = k_{1} k_{2}
\end{align}
$$

*  *  *
Nick Rowe: Because there are two flows of money (a flow out and a flow in), there are two equilibrium conditions.
These two equilibrium conditions are exactly $P_{1} : AD \rightleftarrows M$ and $P_{2} : M \rightleftarrows AS$. If money moves faster than either AD or AS, then we can derive a demand curve for the former and a supply curve for the latter by solving the differential equations:

$$
\begin{align}
P_{1} \equiv \frac{dAD}{dM} & = k_{1} \; \frac{AD_{0}}{\langle M \rangle}\\
P_{2} \equiv \frac{dM}{dAS} & = k_{2} \; \frac{\langle M \rangle}{AS_{0}}
\end{align}
$$

and defining $\Delta X \equiv \langle X \rangle - X_{0}$. They look like this:


Or all together on one graph:


Where $\langle M \rangle$ parameterizes our location along each curve. Since $\langle M \rangle$ can only have one value, in equilibrium we will find ourselves at the point where they are the same (as constructed, the intersection of the two curves).

*  *  *
Nick Rowe: Then remember that exchange is voluntary, so that actual quantity traded is whichever is less: quantity demanded; or quantity supplied.
This is effectively the statement that information received can only be as great as information sent (at least on one direction, $I(AD) \geq I(AS)$), so that our equilibrium conditions (and therefore the curves above) become upper bounds:

$$
\begin{align}
\frac{dAD}{dM} & \leq k_{1} \; \frac{AD}{M}\\
\frac{dM}{dAS} & \leq k_{2} \; \frac{M}{AS}
\end{align}
$$

This is non-ideal information transfer. Note that this also is where market failure enters (described in more detail here).

*  *  *
Nick Rowe: A good simple place to start would be with MV=PY for the AD curve ...
The information equilibrium relationship $P_{1} : AD \rightleftarrows M$ yields this because

$$
\begin{align}
P_{1} = & k_{1} \; \frac{AD}{M}\\
M \left( \frac{P_{1}}{k} \right) = & AD \equiv \Pi Y \\
M V = & \Pi Y
\end{align}
$$

where we've defined $V \equiv P_{1}/k$. Note that this works empirically to leading order in an ensemble of random markets. For 1000 random markets, we have the model versus the data in the graph below:


*  *  *
Nick Rowe: And if you don't start with money, monetary exchange, and AD and AS, you are doing macro wrong.
Now we come back to my issue. The thing is that inserting monetary exchange in the AD/AS diagram is effectively using mathematics, not behavioral relationships. In a sense, it's an identity (the chain rule or $M/M = 1$). And you can actually derive the aggregate supply/aggregate demand diagram above without resorting to money (from $\Pi : AD \rightleftarrows AS$ alone, by assuming one or the other responds slowly to changes in the other [1]).

Therefore asserting that you need to include money is making an assumption that the important and interesting macro dynamics are in the monetary exchanges $AD \rightleftarrows M$ and $M \rightleftarrows AS$. It is possible this is true, but that is something for empirical analysis, not theoretical fiat.

Indeed, interest rates can be described by a formally similar set of relationships

$$
\begin{align}
p : I & \rightleftarrows M\\
r & \rightleftarrows p
\end{align}
$$

where $I$ is investment (GPDI). This works out empirically:


And in fact the IS-LM model can be derived from the monetary exchange AD/AS model above as an effective description at low inflation (where the monetary component becomes unobservable). Therefore Nick's assertion isn't as ironclad as he'd like to think. And there's some decent empirical evidence (see above) that the information equilibrium model captures the phenomena fairly well.

*  *  *

Update 20 January 2017

Brad DeLong's take.

Footnotes:

[1] That diagram looks like this (instead of $\langle M \rangle$ on the two curves, you have the ensemble averages of AD and AS):


No comments:

Post a Comment

Comments are welcome. Please see the Moderation and comment policy.

Also, try to avoid the use of dollar signs as they interfere with my setup of mathjax. I left it set up that way because I think this is funny for an economics blog. You can use € or £ instead.

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.