Thursday, June 20, 2019

Resolving the Cambridge capital controversy with logic


So I wrote somewhat tongue-in-cheek blog post a few years ago titled "Resolving the Cambridge capital controversy with abstract algebra" [RCCC I] that called the Cambridge Capital Controversy [CCC] for Cambridge, UK in terms of the original debate they they were having — summarized by Joan Robinson's claim that you can't really add apples and oranges (or in this case printing presses and drill presses) to form a sensible definition of capital. I used a bit of group theory and the information equilibrium framework to show that you can't simply add up factors of production. I mentioned at the bottom of that post that there are really easy ways around it — including a partition function approach in my paper — but Cambridge, MA (Solow and Samuelson) never made those arguments.

On the Cambridge, MA side no one seemed to care because the theory seemed to "work" (debatable). A few years passed and eventually Samuelson conceded Robinson and Sraffa were in fact right about their re-switching arguments. A short summary is available in an NBER paper from Baqaae and Farhi, but what interested me about that paper was that the particular way they illustrated it made it clear to me that the partition function approach also gets around the re-switching arguments. So I wrote that up in a blog post with another snarky title "Resolving the Cambridge capital controversy with MaxEnt" [RCCC II] (a partition function is maximum entropy distribution or MaxEnt).

This of course opened a can of worms on Twitter when I tweeted out the link to my post. The first volley was several people saying Cobb-Douglas functions were just a consequence of accounting identities or that they fit any data — a lot of which was based on papers by Anwar Shaikh (in particular the "humbug" production function). I added an update to my post saying these arguments were disingenuous — and in my view academic fraud because they rely on a visual misrepresentation of data as well as a elision of the direction of mathematical implication. Solow pointed out the former in his 1974 response to Shaikh's "humbug" paper (as well as the fact that Shaikh's data shows labor output is independent of capital which would render the entire discussion moot if true), but Shaikh has continued to misrepresent "humbug" until at least 2017 in an INET interview on YouTube.

The funny thing is that I never really cared about the CCC — my interest on this blog is research into economic theory based on information theory. RCCC I and RCCC II were both primarily about how you would go about addressing the underlying questions in the information equilibrium framework. However, the subsequent volleys have brought up even more illogical or plainly false arguments against aggregate production functions that seem to have sprouted in the Post-Keynesian walled garden. I believe it's because "mainstream" academic econ has long since abandoned arguing about it, and like my neglected back yard a large number of weeds have grown up. This post is going to do a bit of weeding.

Constant factor shares!

Several comments brought up that Cobb-Douglas production functions can fit any data assuming (empirically observed) constant factor shares. However, this is just a claim that the gradient 

$$
\nabla = \left( \frac{\partial}{\partial \log L} , \frac{\partial}{\partial \log K} \right)
$$

is constant, which a fortiori implies a Cobb-Douglas production function

$$
\log Y = a \log L + b \log K + c
$$

A backtrack is that it's only constant factor shares in the neighborhood of observed values, but that just means Cobb-Douglas functions are a local approximation (i.e. the tangent plane in log-linear space) to the observed region. Either way, saying "with constant factor shares, Cobb Douglas can fit any data" is saying vacuously "data that fits a Cobb-Douglas function can be fit with a Cobb-Douglas function". Leontief production functions also have constant factor shares locally, but in fact have two tangent planes, which just retreats to the local description (data that is locally Cobb-Douglas can be fit with a local Cobb-Douglas function).

Aggregate production functions don't exist!

The denial that the functions even exist is by far the most interesting argument, but it's still not logically sound. At least it's not disingenuous — it could just use a bit of interdisciplinary insight. Jo Michell linked me to a paper by Jonathan Temple with the nonthreatening title "Aggregate production functions and growth economics" (although the filename is "Aggreg Prod Functions Dont Exist.Temple.pdf" and the first line of the abstract is "Rigorous approaches to aggregation indicate that aggregate production functions do not exist except in unlikely special cases.")

However, not too far in (Section 2, second paragraph) it makes a logical error of extrapolating from $N = 2$ to $N \gg 1$:
It is easy to show that if the two sectors each have Cobb-Douglas production technologies, and if the exponents on inputs differ across sectors, there cannot be a Cobb-Douglas aggregate production function.
It's explained how the argument proceeds in a footnote:
The way to see this is to write down the aggregate labour share as a weighted average of labour shares in the two sectors. If the structure of output changes, the weights and the aggregate labour share will also change, and hence there cannot be an aggregate Cobb-Douglas production function (which would imply a constant labour share at the aggregate level).
This is true for $N = 2$, because the change of one "labor share state" (specified by $\alpha_{i}$ for a individual sector $y_{i} \sim k^{\alpha_{i}}$) implies an overall change in the ensemble average labor share state $\langle \alpha \rangle$. However, this is a bit like saying if you have a two-atom ideal gas, the kinetic energy of one of the atoms can change and so the average kinetic energy of the two-atom gas doesn't exist therefore (rigorously!) there is no such thing as temperature (i.e. a well defined kinetic energy $\sim k T$) for an ideal gas in general with more than two atoms ($N \gg 1$) except in unlikely special cases.

I was quite surprised that econ has disproved the existence of thermodynamics!

Joking aside, if you have more than two sectors, it is possible you could have an empirically stable distribution over labor share states $\alpha_{i}$ and a partition function (details of the approach appear in my paper):

$$
Z(\kappa) = \sum_{i} e^{- \kappa \alpha_{i}}
$$

take $\kappa \equiv \log (1+ (k-k_{0})/k_{0})$ which means

$$
\langle y \rangle \sim k^{\langle \alpha \rangle}
$$

where the ensemble average is

$$
\langle X \rangle \equiv \frac{1}{Z} \sum_{i} \hat{X} e^{- \kappa \alpha_{i}}
$$

There are likely more ways than this partition function approach based on information equilibrium to get around the $N = 2$ case, but we only need to construct one example to disprove nonexistence. Basically this means that unless the output structure of a single firm affects the whole economy, it is entirely possible that the output structure of an ensemble of firms could have a stable distribution of labor share states. You cannot logically rule it out.

What's interesting to me is that in a whole host of situations, the distributions of these economic states appear to be stable (and in some cases in an unfortunate pun, stable distributions). For some specific examples, we can look at profit rate states and stock growth rate states.

Now you might not believe these empirical results. Regardless, the logical argument is not valid unless your model of the economy is unrealistically extremely simplistic (like modeling a gas with a single atom — not too unlike the unrealistic representative agent picture). There is of course the possibility that empirically this doesn't work (much like it doesn't work for a whole host of non-equilibrium thermodynamics processes). But Jonathan Temple's paper is a bunch of wordy prose with the odd equation — it does not address the empirical question. In fact, Temple re-iterates one of the defenses of the aggregate production function approaches that has vexed these theoretical attempts to knock them down (section 4, first paragraph):
One of the traditional defenses of aggregate production functions is a pragmatic one: they may not exist, but empirically they ‘seem to work’.
They of course would seem to work if economies are made up of more than two firms (or sectors) and have relatively stable distributions of labor share states.

To put it yet another way, Temple's argument relies on a host of unrealistic assumptions about an economy — that we know the distribution isn't stable, and that there are only a few sectors, and that the output structure of these few firms changes regularly enough to require a new estimate of the exponent $\alpha$ but not regularly enough that the changes create a temporal distribution of states.

Fisher! Aggregate production functions are highly constrained!

There's a lot of references that trace all the way back to Fisher (1969) "The existence of aggregate production functions" and several people who mentioned Fisher or work derived from his papers. The paper is itself a survey of restrictions believed to constrain aggregate production functions, but it seems to have been written from the perspective that an economy is a highly mathematical construct that can either only be described by $C^{2}$ functions or not at all. In a later section (Sec. 6) talking about whether maybe aggregate production functions can be good approximations, Fisher says:
approximations could only result if [the approximation] ... exhibited very large rates of change ... In less technical language, the derivatives would have to wiggle violently up and down all the time.
Heaven forbid were that the case!



He cites in a footnote the rather ridiculous example of $\lambda \sin (x/\lambda)$ (locally $C^{2}$!) — I get the feeling he was completely unaware of stochastic calculus or quantum mechanics and therefore could not imagine a smooth macroeconomy made up of noisy components, only a few pathological examples from his real analysis course in college. Again, a nice case for some interdisciplinary exchange! I wrote a post some years ago about the $C^{2}$ view economists seem to take versus a far more realistic noisy approach in the context of the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model. In any case, why exactly should we expect firm level production functions to be $C^{2}$ functions that add to a $C^{2}$ function?

One of the constraints Fisher notes is that individual firm production functions (for the $i^{th}$ firm) must take a specific additive form:

$$
f_{i}(K_{i}, L_{i}) = \phi_{i}(K_{i}) + \psi_{i}(L_{i})
$$

This is probably true if you think of an economy as one large $C^{2}$ function that has to factor (mathematically, like, say, a polynomial) into individual firms. But like Temple's argument, it denies the possibility that there can be stable distributions of states $(\alpha_{i}, \beta_{i})$ for individual firm production functions (that even might change over time!) such that 

$$
Y_{i} = f_{i}(K_{i}, L_{i}) = K_{i}^{\alpha_{i}}L_{i}^{\beta_{i}}
$$

but

$$
\langle Y \rangle \sim K^{\langle \alpha \rangle} L^{\langle \beta \rangle}
$$



 

The left/first picture is a bunch of random production functions with beta distributed exponents. The right/second picture is an average of 10 of them. In the limit of an infinite number of firms, constant returns to scale hold (i.e. $\langle \alpha \rangle + \langle \beta \rangle \simeq 0.35 + 0.65 = 1$) at the macro level — however individual firms aren't required to have constant returns to scale (many don't in this example). In fact, none of the individual firms have to have any of the properties of the aggregate production function. (You don't really have to impose that constraint at either scale — and in fact, in the whole Solow model works much better empirically in terms of nominal quantities and without constant returns to scale.) Since these are simple functions, they don't have that many properties but  we can include things like constant factor shares or constant returns to scale.

The information-theoretic partition function approach actually has a remarkable self-similarity between macro (i.e. aggregate level) and micro (i.e. individual or individual firm level) — this self-similarity is behind the reason why Cobb-Douglas or diagrammatic ("crossing curve") models at the macro scale aren't obviously implausible.

Both the arguments of Temple and Fisher seem to rest on strong assumptions about economies constructed from clean, noiseless, abstract functions — and either a paucity or surfeit of imagination (I'm not sure). It's a kind of love-hate relationship with neoclassical economics — working within its confines to try to show that it's flawed. A lot of these results are cases of what I personally would call mathiness. I'm sure Paul Romer might think they're fine, but to me they sound like an all-too-earnest undergraduate math major fresh out of real analysis trying to tell us what's what. Sure, man, individual firms production functions are continuous and differentiable additive functions. So what exactly have you been smoking?

These constraints on production functions from Fisher and Temple actually remind me a lot of Steve Keen's definition of an equilibrium that isn't attainable — it's mathematically forbidden! It's probably not a good definition of equilibrium if you can't even come up with a theoretical case that satisfies it. Fisher and Temple can't really come up with a theoretical production function that meets all their constraints besides the trivial "all firms are the same" function. It's funny that Fisher actually touches on that in one of his footnotes (#31):
Honesty requires me to state that I have no clear idea what technical differences actually look like. Capital augmentation seems unduly restrictive, however. If it held, all firms would produce the same market basket of outputs and hire the same relative collection of labors.
But the bottom line is that these claims to have exhausted all possibilities are just not true! I get the feeling that people have already made up their minds which side of the CCC they stand on, and it doesn't take much to confirm their biases so they don't ask questions after e.g. Temple's two sector economy. That settles it then! Well, no ... as there might be more than two sectors. Maybe even three!


7 comments:

  1. aren't you just using the word "exist" in a difference sense to Temple? I am pretty sure Jon is just adopting the language of those he is trying to debate, and acknowledging a point they make - people who use the word "exist" to mean (something like) you usually can't write down a small set of 'micro' production functions and from them analytically derive an aggregate function. I think you agree that's true, you just don't think it's interesting and not a very sensible use of the word "exist"

    I am pretty sure Jon would be perfectly happy with the idea that if you have lots of different firms it makes sense to say an aggregate production function exists, meaning something like it emerges as a regularity across the lot (of however you'd put it). I say this because I have talked to him about papers that showed production functions emerging in that way, and he thought they were great. I will try to find the ones I mean, later.

    Jon does not think economies are constructed from clean, noiseless, abstract functions, he's just saying if you want to look at things that that way you can't derive neat aggregate production functions in the way some people want to - I don't think he believes that's a devastating point. He is trying to saying to the people he's debating with "ok, I accept that, but I still want to argue aggregate production functions have their uses".


    Jon was my PhD supervisor, I think it was me that introduced his papers to these twitter debates.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. "people who use the word "exist" to mean (something like) you usually can't write down a small set of 'micro' production functions and from them analytically derive an aggregate function. I think you agree that's true ..."

      I do not think that is true! I am realizing that there is a misconception out there that using a partition function and statistical distributions is "not analytic" (or even "empirical") when it is just as analytic as using real functions and taking limits.

      In the argument he makes for N = 2, it literally fails for N = 3 because you could adjust the other two sectors. In that case, you have to assume one production function changes and the other two do not change in such a way as to restore the aggregate function.

      Using a distribution and N >> 1 makes 1) the change of a single firm irrelevant to the total (~ 1/N), and 2) makes any change of multiple firms such that the distribution (and therefore the aggregate) changes exceedingly unlikely. And that result is entirely analytical just like the fluctuation theorem.

      Let's say the original argument is that you built a production function out of Legos. If you just have two, changing one changes the whole production function. With three, it's possible to change out one Lego and still have the same structure arise if the others change. But for a large number, you basically have to come in and deliberately smash the Lego structure and say "See, Now it's broken!"

      In fact, that's a good metaphor for a lot of these efforts to "disprove" aggregate production functions. Yes, if you deliberately smash them, they don't exist. But there are often multiple ways to get around the smashing arguments — often it seems it's because the authors of those arguments have econ educations that focus around the theory of functions. But a lack of imagination of a solution does not disprove existence.

      This is not to say some effect can't come in an smash the distribution — I actually think that's what recessions might be, and it takes correlating most of the agents in the market to accomplish. But people have mob behavior, so this is not implausible. But it is a specific mechanism, and saying production functions aggregate except in recessions is probably even a caveat Solow would have had no problem with.

      (Side note, that's almost the kind of assumption you have to make to get the 2 or 3 sector disproofs to work: if one sector radically changes its production function — what's causing that? And why doesn't it affect the other sectors? And if it's a good idea, why don't the other sectors follow along?)

      Now it is true that saying there's a distribution of firm production functions that aggregate raises the question of why does that distribution exist? Or even, does it exist in reality? I think there's some evidence they do (cited above), but it's debatable. However, it's logically possible and is no less analytic than linear combinations of functions.

      Delete
  2. I still think this is just talking at cross purposes. If you have 3 micro you can adjust them to preserve the aggregate, but isn't that a special case, you need to make that adjustment just right? When people are talking about these functions not existing, they are not thinking of statistical distributions, I don't even think they are talking about taking limits of real functions (although I am not sure). You are no doubt right they ought to be. I think all they are saying is more like "suppose you had an economy that consisted of a small number of sectors with different production functions, you can't add them up and get a perfect neat aggregate production function" - again, you are no doubt right that by no means exhausts the possibilities and isn't a very useful way to look at the world. I just think if you want to interpret what people write in the way they mean, that's what they mean.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Yes, the case where you change 1 and adjust the other 2 is a "special case", but it's actually a more likely special case (i.e. the 3 firms maintain a statistical distribution due to some macro constraint) than the "non-special" case where only one changes. Could a sector really decide to change the structure of its production to be anything it wants? I'm sure every firm would decide to switch to alpha = 0.99999 making production independent of labor if that was the case. More likely, there are limits based on the capacity of the economy as a whole — and that constraint sets up the distribution making the "special case" more likely than arbitrary change.

      I guess I am taking exception to the way this is worded. A maximalist conclusion is given that is unsupported ...

      "Rigorous approaches to aggregation indicate that aggregate production functions do not exist except in unlikely special cases."

      If you rephrases this to say:

      One particular argument about an unrealistic formulation of aggregation indicates that aggregate production functions do not exist in those unlikely special cases.

      I'd be fine with it. And it seems like you and you think Prof. Temple might agree with that statement ...

      It sounds illogical to me to allow a production function to change (per the counter argument) once in one specific way, but disallow any other changes or assume away an ensemble. Can we really assume away a statistical treatment when you assume an event that itself would be a stochastic event? The picture of the economy in the counterexample is a two sector economy where the government steps in an tells one of the sectors to change the way it does business — the sector is not responding to a price change or other macro event, but some sort of planned change (i.e. not statistical because we're disallowing it for sake of argument). How can we then just assume the external validity of that result?

      Delete
  3. Yes I shouldn't speak for Jon, perhaps he gives more weight to the 'doesn't exist' claim than I imagine, perhaps when he wrote that the alternatives approaches you outline had not occurred to him. However I think I can say for sure that there are some people out there who say "mainstream economics is WRONG aggregate production functions DON'T EVEN EXIST" and he is arguing: okay I'll give you that, but that's not the end of the story, they could still be useful empirically and we can learn things about the world by employing them.

    if you don't mind, just for my satisfaction, in say the 3-sector case, I imagine most economists would regard the production functions as more like an endowment than a choice - e.g. for automotive it so happens to look like this, for agriculture like that, for healthcare like so - and the argument there would be that unless those endowed functions happen to fit together in particular way, you couldn't neatly combine them into a production function, so I don't understand your argument that 'special case' is more likely than not, because of some economic constraints.

    I should confess, my personal belief is that I don't know where an aggregate production function being useful/reasonably accurate empirically ends, and it being useless/failing empirically begins. I do think it's likely that different types of production (let's say sectors, for ease) combine inputs to create outputs in different ways, so if you ask "what happens if you add capital to the economy?" then it is likely to matter which sectors you are adding it to, which to my mind speaks against an aggregate production function being helpful. I can sort of loosely intuit that prices and behaviour might move around so that no matter what sector you add capital to, what happens in aggregate look reasonably consistent, but I'd like to see a toy model which explains how that might work.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Funny thing is that I actually think the Solow model production functions (and in general) is wrong empirically. It's a remarkably good model if you drop using real variables and the constant returns to scale assumptions. (Note that it makes far more sense to drop the constant returns assumption if you switch to nominal variables because the "replication" arguments for constant returns only apply to real quantities). It's also interesting in that it can be wrong in the sense that different measures of capital don't aren't as accurate as each other — implying there's something there.

      As I said, the 3-sector case definitely has possibilities that do not satisfy aggregation. And it may well be empirically true that real economies somehow endow firms with production functions that don't aggregate. Where I'm coming from, those cases that don't aggregate look like pathological cases that might prevent a general existence theorem, but they neither seem likely (to me) nor do they prove a general non-existence theorem.

      I would love to do a simulation at some point — and was in the process of putting together some random network diagrams. One of the key points that at least gives me some confidence about being right here is that if labor and capital contain all of the information about output (i.e. output is some recipe of different types of labor and capital steps), then something like a Cobb-Douglas function must result from some basic information theory arguments. Most of the pathological cases represent information loss or some other non-equivalence in the information in labor and capital and the information in the output. It's true there might be hidden variables and hidden information (i.e. additional factors of production)! But that's not the argument being had here which assumes that labor and capital are inputs at the sector scale.

      Delete
    2. Oh, and as a fun side note: in that nominal model that works well, it's not capital that sets prices — labor does. The price in each individual sector comes from the p_i = dY_i/dL = k Y_i/L piece and the aggregate < p_i > ~ price level.

      Delete

Comments are welcome. Please see the Moderation and comment policy.

Also, try to avoid the use of dollar signs as they interfere with my setup of mathjax. I left it set up that way because I think this is funny for an economics blog. You can use € or £ instead.

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.