Unemployment by race (white = blue, black = yellow) and dynamic equilibrium (red, green). |
I can't remember where I saw it on Twitter while I was on vacation, but someone graphed the most recent unemployment data by race. One of the things I noticed was the similarities in the shape of the time series. Could the disparities be explained by a single dynamic equilibrium, but with different initial conditions? Is the reason black unemployment is high today simply because it was high in the past?
It turns out the answer is basically yes.
Unlike the case of different education levels where the shape is basically the same but the dynamic equilibrium rates – the roughly constant rate of falling unemployment after a shock – are sufficiently different as to be distinguishable, the dynamic equilibrium rate for black and white unemployment is the same within model error (they are both approximately 0.09 and differ by only 0.003, see the addendum). In the graph at the top of this post, the same dynamic equilibrium fit (shown in red and green) does a reasonable job explaining both black and white unemployment (yellow and blue, respectively).
Since the model deals in logarithms, the two time series are essentially scaled versions of each other (instead of a linear model, in which they'd be shifted versions of each other). The underlying matching model is therefore the same, just with different initial conditions (higher black unemployment in 1972 than white). If white unemployment and black unemployment had been the same in 1972, then they'd be roughly the same today.
Since both white and black employment (according to this model) are hit by the same shocks, this means that black unemployment will never fall to the same level as white unemployment without some kind of intervention. Additionally, this intervention cannot be racially blind because it has to decrease black unemployment but not decrease white unemployment as much (because that would not improve the ratio). It would therefore take the form of some kind of reparations (e.g. a black-only WPA).
Addendum: Methodology
I used four different methods to apply the dynamic equilibrium model (described in detail here). I fit the entire dynamic equilibrium either to white unemployment, or black unemployment and then used that fit ‒ call it f(t), such that exp(f(t)) = u(t) with u(t) being the applicable unemployment rate ‒ to fit to the other unemployment rate u*(t). In that second fit, I used a log-linear model:
so that u*(t) = exp(f*(t)) = exp(f(t) + a t + b). However I took a = 0 in one case (same EQ), and fit a to the data in the other. Therefore a measures the discrepancy from the dynamic equilibrium α (measuring the roughly constant logarithmic slope of the falling unemployment). The measured rates were:
− 0.092 = α
− 0.095 = α+a
+ 0.003 = a
Fit to black unemployment
− 0.086 = α
− 0.083 = α + a
− 0.003 = a
In both cases, black unemployment fell faster than white unemployment (i.e. the matching function performed better).
* = black, a fit to u*(t)
* = black, a = 0
* = white, a fit to u*(t)
* = white, a = 0
The results were largely similar (within the error of the model), so I've relegated these graphs to this addendum. Here are the results (the fit data u(t) is blue, the model f(t) is red, the other unemployment data u*(t) is yellow and the other model f*(t) is green):
No comments:
Post a Comment
Comments are welcome. Please see the Moderation and comment policy.
Also, try to avoid the use of dollar signs as they interfere with my setup of mathjax. I left it set up that way because I think this is funny for an economics blog. You can use € or £ instead.
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.